TY - JOUR
T1 - How much can taxes help selfish routing?
AU - Cole, Richard
AU - Dodis, Yevgeniy
AU - Roughgarden, Tim
N1 - Funding Information:
A preliminary version of this paper appeared in the Proceedings of the 4th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, June 2003. ∗Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (R. Cole), [email protected] (Y. Dodis), [email protected] (T. Roughgarden). 1Supported in part by NSF grant CCR0105678. 2 Supported in part by an NSF CAREER Award. 3Supported in part by ONR grant N00014-04-1-0725 and DARPA grant W911NF-04-9-0001. Most of this research was performed while the author was visiting NYU and supported by ONR grant N00014-98-1-0589 as a postdoctoral researcher at Cornell University.
PY - 2006/5
Y1 - 2006/5
N2 - We study economic incentives for influencing selfish behavior in networks. We consider a model of selfish routing in which the latency experienced by network traffic on an edge of the network is a function of the edge congestion, and network users are assumed to selfishly route traffic on minimum-latency paths. The quality of a routing of traffic is historically measured by the sum of all travel times, also called the total latency. It is well known that the outcome of selfish routing (a flow at Nash equilibrium) does not minimize the total latency, and that marginal cost pricing-charging each network user for the congestion effects caused by its presence-eliminates the inefficiency of selfish routing. However, the principle of marginal cost pricing assumes that taxes cause no disutility to network users; this is appropriate only when collected taxes can be feasibly returned (directly or indirectly) to the users. If this assumption does not hold and we wish to minimize the total user disutility (latency plus taxes paid)-the total cost-how should we price the network edges? Intuition may suggest that taxes can never improve the cost of a Nash equilibrium, but the famous Braess's Paradox shows this intuition to be incorrect. We consider strategies for pricing network edges to reduce the cost of a Nash equilibrium. Since levying a sufficiently large tax on an edge effectively removes it from the network, our study generalizes previous work on designing networks for selfish users [T. Roughgarden, Designing networks for selfish users is hard, in: Proceedings of the 42nd Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science (FOCS), 2001, pp. 472-481 (full version to appear in Journal of Computer and System Sciences)]. In this paper, we prove the following results. •In a large class of networks-including all networks with linear latency functions-marginal cost taxes do not improve the cost of a Nash equilibrium. •The largest-possible benefit from taxes does not exceed that from edge removals. In every network with linear latency functions, the benefit of taxes cannot exceed that of removing edges. There are networks with nonlinear latency functions, however, in which taxes are radically more powerful than edge removals. •For every ε{lunate} > 0, there is no ( frac(4, 3) - ε{lunate} )-approximation algorithm for computing optimal taxes, even in networks with linear latency functions (assuming P ≠ NP).
AB - We study economic incentives for influencing selfish behavior in networks. We consider a model of selfish routing in which the latency experienced by network traffic on an edge of the network is a function of the edge congestion, and network users are assumed to selfishly route traffic on minimum-latency paths. The quality of a routing of traffic is historically measured by the sum of all travel times, also called the total latency. It is well known that the outcome of selfish routing (a flow at Nash equilibrium) does not minimize the total latency, and that marginal cost pricing-charging each network user for the congestion effects caused by its presence-eliminates the inefficiency of selfish routing. However, the principle of marginal cost pricing assumes that taxes cause no disutility to network users; this is appropriate only when collected taxes can be feasibly returned (directly or indirectly) to the users. If this assumption does not hold and we wish to minimize the total user disutility (latency plus taxes paid)-the total cost-how should we price the network edges? Intuition may suggest that taxes can never improve the cost of a Nash equilibrium, but the famous Braess's Paradox shows this intuition to be incorrect. We consider strategies for pricing network edges to reduce the cost of a Nash equilibrium. Since levying a sufficiently large tax on an edge effectively removes it from the network, our study generalizes previous work on designing networks for selfish users [T. Roughgarden, Designing networks for selfish users is hard, in: Proceedings of the 42nd Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science (FOCS), 2001, pp. 472-481 (full version to appear in Journal of Computer and System Sciences)]. In this paper, we prove the following results. •In a large class of networks-including all networks with linear latency functions-marginal cost taxes do not improve the cost of a Nash equilibrium. •The largest-possible benefit from taxes does not exceed that from edge removals. In every network with linear latency functions, the benefit of taxes cannot exceed that of removing edges. There are networks with nonlinear latency functions, however, in which taxes are radically more powerful than edge removals. •For every ε{lunate} > 0, there is no ( frac(4, 3) - ε{lunate} )-approximation algorithm for computing optimal taxes, even in networks with linear latency functions (assuming P ≠ NP).
KW - Game theory in networks
KW - Inefficiency of equilibria
KW - Marginal cost taxes
KW - Pricing
KW - Selfish routing
UR - http://www.scopus.com/inward/record.url?scp=33645799677&partnerID=8YFLogxK
UR - http://www.scopus.com/inward/citedby.url?scp=33645799677&partnerID=8YFLogxK
U2 - 10.1016/j.jcss.2005.09.010
DO - 10.1016/j.jcss.2005.09.010
M3 - Article
AN - SCOPUS:33645799677
SN - 0022-0000
VL - 72
SP - 444
EP - 467
JO - Journal of Computer and System Sciences
JF - Journal of Computer and System Sciences
IS - 3
ER -